For years I've been vaguely aware of the Catholic Land Movement that was initiated in England in the interbellum period between the two great world wars. Its promotors included G.K. Chesterton and Hilaire Belloc, writers whom I've admired for years. Their project, in short, was to foster a return to the land. They saw the rise of industrialism in England -- the self-styled "workshop of the world" -- as being inherently inimical to basic human thriving. Man has "an affinity for reality," one of Land Movement's promotors argued. "The elements of life -- the cleansing earth, the seasons, the contact with primary things -- are necessary to sanity."
The highly idealistic Land Movement sought to train Catholic men in the agricultural arts and settle them on small plots of land, both to farm and to raise their families in small, closely knit, faith-centered communities. Then World War II intervened: the world changed dramatically, many of the most prominent promotors died, and, sadly, the budding movement died out.
But the Land Movement's founding documents endure in a book entitled Flee to the Fields, which Rosemary purchased for me last month as a Christmas present. Having started reading the book just yesterday, I'm only two essays into the slim volume. But I'm so taken by the ideas expressed therein that I'm inspired to restart the old Garlic and Sapphires blog. My intention here is to write a series of posts on particularly pivotal insights that I've come across in my reading. In each entry I'll lay out in the insight in context, and then I'll reflect on it in light of my own farming experience. Perhaps I'll be enthusiastic enough to write daily; perhaps life will distract me, and I'll slow down.
***********
The problem of simple versus compound interest
The first essay in Flee to the Fields was composed by Herbert Shove, who was a British naval commander in both world wars as well as a self-taught economic theorist. Among many other insights, Shove notes that modern capitalism thrives off of compound interest. The idea is that profit is calculated from ever-increasing principal balance. With burgeoning enterprises, this makes sense because such businesses have the potential to be ever larger; they are held in check only by the market forces of supply and demand. If there is a demand for flat-screen televisions, then a maker of flat-screen televisions can chart an upward trajectory in production, consistently showing a profit that compounds as the business grows in size. While one may certainly question whether such a trajectory can continue indefinitely, even in industry, that would be a matter for another essay.
What works (at least temporarily) in industry, Shove argues, does not work in agriculture. A farm may briefly take on the trappings of compounding profits by improving its efficiency to squeeze more out of a flock, a herd, or a parcel of land. But eventually the interest stops compounding because nothing more can be squeezed out of what is available without adulterating the quality of whatever is produced. The principal is what the principal is: so many cows produce so many hundredweight of milk per year; so many acres yield so many bushels of wheat per season. There are limits to what the land can produce or the size that an operation can be. Interest in farming is simple, Shrove writes, not compound, because the principal remains constant.
When agriculture is run like an industry and has industrial profits demanded of it, it's quickly run into the ground. Whereas industry turns a profit by "reducing the time cycle of manufacture," agriculture is bound by a "rigid seasonal time factor." Also, both industry and agriculture reduce their wage bill by turning to mechanization. But whereas industry pays for that mechanization by expansion and by diversification into an near endless array of manufactured goods, expansion in agriculture can only go so far because a nation only needs so much milk, so much wheat, and so much corn and soy.
And thus capitalistic agriculture-as-industry rapidly becomes a dead-end. "The seasonal 'simple interest' return from land must, as the speeding-up process continues, lag ever further behind the cyclic 'compound interest' return from trade or manufacture."
***********
No comments:
Post a Comment